×

Risk aversion in a model of endogenous growth. (English) Zbl 1368.91148

Summary: Despite the evidence on incomplete financial markets and substantial risk being borne by innovators, current models of growth through creative destruction predominantly model innovators’ as risk neutral. Risk aversion is expected to reduce the incentive to innovate and we might fear that without insurance innovation completely disappears in the long run. The present paper introduces risk averse agents into an occupational choice model of endogenous growth in which insurance against failure to innovate is not available. We derive a clear negative relationship between the level of risk aversion and long run growth. Surprisingly, we show that in an equilibrium there exists a cut-off value of risk aversion below which the growth rate of the mass of innovators tends to a strictly positive constant. In this case, innovation persists on the long run and consumption per capita grows at a strictly positive rate. On the other hand, for levels of risk aversion above the cut-off value, the economy eventually stagnates.

MSC:

91B62 Economic growth models
PDFBibTeX XMLCite
Full Text: DOI Link

References:

[1] Acemoglu, D., Introduction to Modern Growth Theory (2009), The MIT Press · Zbl 1158.91001
[2] Aghion, P.; Angeletos, G.-M.; Banerjee, A.; Manova, K., Volatility and growth: Credit constraints and the composition of investment, J. Monetary Econ., 57, 246-265 (2010)
[3] Aghion, P.; Bolton, P., A theory of trickle-down growth and development, Rev. Econom. Stud., 64, 151-172 (1997) · Zbl 0890.90023
[4] Aghion, P.; Howitt, P., A model of growth through creative destruction, Econometrica, 60, 323-351 (1992) · Zbl 0825.90147
[5] Aghion, P.; Howitt, P., Endogenous Growth Theory (1998), MIT Press: MIT Press Cambridge, MA
[6] Aiyagari, S. R., Uninsured idiosyncratic risk and aggregate saving, Quart. J. Econ., 109, 659-684 (1994)
[7] Akerlof, G. A., The Market for “Lemons”: Quality uncertainty and the market mechanism, Quart. J. Econ., 84, 488-500 (1970)
[8] Alan, S.; Attanasio, O.; Browning, M., Estimating Euler equations with noisy data: two exact GMM estimators, J. Appl. Econometrics, 24, 309-324 (2009)
[9] Alan, S.; Browning, M., Estimating intertemporal allocation parameters using synthetic residual estimation, Rev. Econom. Stud., 77, 1231-1261 (2010) · Zbl 1202.91262
[10] Alcalá, F.; Ciccone, A., Trade and productivity, Quart. J. Econ., 119, 613-646 (2004) · Zbl 1109.91380
[11] Angeletos, G.-M., Uninsured idiosyncratic investment risk and aggregate saving, Rev. Econ. Dynam., 10, 1-30 (2007)
[13] Attanasio, O. P.; Weber, G., Consumption and saving: models of intertemporal allocation and their implications for public policy, Technical Report (2010), National Bureau of Economic Research
[14] Banerjee, A. V.; Newman, A. F., Risk-bearing and the theory of income distribution, Rev. Econom. Stud., 58, 211-235 (1991) · Zbl 0726.90017
[15] Banerjee, A. V.; Newman, A. F., Occupational choice and the process of development, J. Polit. Econ., 101, 274-298 (1993)
[16] Barro, R. J.; Sala-i-Martin, X., Economic Growth (2003), MIT Press
[17] Blanchard, O. J., Debt, deficits, and finite horizons, J. Polit. Econ., 93, 223-247 (1985)
[18] Caggese, A., Entrepreneurial risk, investment, and innovation, J. Financ. Econ., 106, 287-307 (2012)
[19] Campbell, J. Y., Asset prices, consumption, and the business cycle, (Handbook of Macroeconomics, Vol. 1 (1999)), 1231-1303
[20] Card, D.; Chetty, R.; Weber, A., Cash-on-hand and competing models of intertemporal behaviour: New evidence from the labor market, Quart. J. Econ., 122, 1511-1560 (2007) · Zbl 1179.91120
[21] Cozzi, G.; Giordani, P., Ambiguity attitude, R&D investments and economic growth, J. Evol. Econ., 21, 303-319 (2011)
[22] Eaton, J.; Kortum, S., Technology, trade, and growth: A unified framework, Eur. Econ. Rev., 45, 742-755 (2001)
[23] Evans, D. S.; Jovanovic, B., An estimated model of entrepreneurial choice under liquidity constraints, J. Polit. Econ., 97, 808-827 (1989)
[24] Galor, O.; Zeira, J., Income distribution and macroeconomics, Rev. Econom. Stud., 60, 35-52 (1993) · Zbl 0825.90194
[25] García-Peñalosa, C.; Wen, J.-F., Redistribution and entrepreneurship with schumpeterian growth, J. Econ. Growth, 13, 57-80 (2008) · Zbl 1136.91520
[26] Ghatak, M.; Jiang, N. N.-H., A simple model of inequality, occupational choice, and development, J. Dev. Econ., 69, 205-226 (2002)
[27] Gourinchas, P.-O.; Parker, J. A., Consumption over the life cycle, Econometrica, 70, 47-89 (2002) · Zbl 1137.91519
[28] Grossman, G. M.; Helpman, E., Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy (1991), MIT Press: MIT Press Cambridge
[29] Grossman, G. M.; Helpman, E., Quality ladders in the theory of growth, Rev. Econom. Stud., 58, 43-61 (1991)
[30] Gruber, J., A tax-based estimate of the elasticity of intertemporal substitution, Technical Report (2006), National Bureau of Economic Research
[31] Hall, B. H., The financing of research and development, Oxford Rev. Econ. Policy, 18, 35-51 (2002)
[32] Hall, B. H.; Lerner, J., The financing of R&D and innovation, (Hall, B. H.; Rosenberg, N., Handbook of The Economics of Innovation, Vol. 1 (2010), North-Holland), 609-639, (Chapter 14)
[33] Jones, C. I., R&D-based models of economic growth, J. Polit. Econ., 103, 759-784 (1995)
[34] Jones, C. I., Growth and ideas, (Aghion, P.; Durlauf, S., Handbook of Economic Growth, Vol. 1 (2005), Elsevier), 1063-1111, (Chapter 16)
[35] Kocherlakota, N. R., The equity premium: It’s still a puzzle, J. Econom. Lit., 34, 42-71 (1996)
[36] Kortum, S., Research, patenting, and technological change, Econometrica, 65, 1389-1419 (1997) · Zbl 0887.90018
[37] Kremer, M., Population growth and technological change: One million B.C. to 1990, Quart. J. Econ., 108, 681-716 (1993)
[38] Levhari, D.; Srinivasan, T. N., Optimal savings under uncertainty, Rev. Econom. Stud., 36, 153-163 (1969)
[39] Merton, R. C., Lifetime portfolio selection under uncertainty: The continuous-time case, Rev. Econ. Stat., 51, 247-257 (1969)
[40] Mookherjee, D.; Ray, D., Persistent inequality, Rev. Econom. Stud., 70, 369-393 (2003) · Zbl 1073.91612
[41] Mulligan, C. B., Capital, interest, and aggregate intertemporal substitution, Technical Report (2002), National Bureau of Economic Research
[42] Patterson, K. D.; Pesaran, B., The intertemporal elasticity of substitution in consumption in the United States and the United Kingdom, Rev. Econ. Stat., 74, 573-584 (1992)
[43] Romer, P. M., Increasing returns and long-run growth, J. Polit. Econ., 94, 1002-1037 (1986)
[44] Romer, P. M., Endogenous technological change, J. Polit. Econ., 98, S71-S102 (1990)
[45] Samuelson, P. S., Lifetime portfolio selection by dynamic stochastic programming, Rev. Econ. Stat., 51, 239-246 (1969)
[46] Segerstrom, P. S., Endogenous growth witout scale effects, Amer. Econ. Rev., 88, 1290-1310 (1998)
[47] Segerstrom, P. S.; Anant, T.; Dinopoulos, E., A schumpeterian model of the product life cycle, Amer. Econ. Rev., 5, 1077-1091 (1990)
[48] Vissing-Jørgensen, A.; Attanasio, O. P., Stock-market participation, intertemporal substitution, and risk-aversion, Amer. Econ. Rev., 93, 383-391 (2003)
[49] Yaari, M. E., Uncertain lifetime, life insurance, and the theory of the consumer, Rev. Econom. Stud., 32, 137-150 (1965)
[50] Yogo, M., Estimating the elasticity of intertemporal substitution when instruments are weak, Rev. Econ. Stat., 86, 797-810 (2004)
[51] Zeira, J., Innovations, patent races and endogenous growth, J. Econ. Growth, 16, 135-156 (2011) · Zbl 1214.91076
This reference list is based on information provided by the publisher or from digital mathematics libraries. Its items are heuristically matched to zbMATH identifiers and may contain data conversion errors. In some cases that data have been complemented/enhanced by data from zbMATH Open. This attempts to reflect the references listed in the original paper as accurately as possible without claiming completeness or a perfect matching.